It Is Not Armed Robbery When Government Takes People's Stuff, It Is Civil Asset Forfeiture
Abstract
Abstract. Civil asset forfeiture allows the police to profit from crime instead of the criminal by seizing a person’s belongings that were used in illegal activity. The police profit from crime by keeping a percentage of the proceeds they seize. This ends up creating some perverse incentives, such as having more police resources go to seize people’s assets instead of fighting crime. Shifting police efforts away from combating hard crime into fighting so-called “victimless crimes” causes an increase in hard crimes as criminals substitute from soft crimes, such as selling drugs, into hard crimes where the chances of being caught are now lower.
Keywords. Theft, Government, Competition.
JEL. H0, H10.
Keywords
References
Baicker, K., & Jacobson, M. (2007). Finders Keepers: Forfeiture Laws, Policing Incentives, and Local Budgets. Journal of Public Economics, 91(11-12), 2113-2136. doi. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.03.009
Barnett, R.E. & Hagel, J. III (eds.). (1977). Assessing the Criminal: Restitution, Retribution, and the Legal Process. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Co.
Barnett W.II, (1989). Subjective cost revisited, Review of Austrian Economics, 3(1), 137-138. doi. 10.1007/BF01539563
Barnett, W.II, & Walter E.B. (2007). Coase and Van Zandt on lighthouses, Public Finance Review, 35(6), 710-733. doi. 10.1177/1091142107302182
Barnett, W.II, & Walter E.B. (2009). Coase and Bertrand on lighthouses, Public Choice; 140(1–2), 1-13. doi. 10.1007/s11127-008-9375-x
Becker, G.S. (1974). Essays in the Economics of Crime and Punishment, NBER, Chapter. [Retrieved from].
Benson, B.L., Rasmussen, D.W., & Sollars, D.L. (1995). Police Bureaucracies, Their Incentives, and the War on Drugs. Public Choice, 83(1). 21-45. doi. 10.1007/BF01047681
Benson, B.L., & Rasmussen, D.W. (1998). Deterrence and Public Policy: Trade-Offs in the Allocation of Police Resources. International Review of Law and Economics, 18(1), 77-100. doi. 10.1016/S0144-8188(97)00059-8
Benson, B.L., Kim, I., & Rasmussen, D.W. (1994). Estimating Deterrence Effects: A Public Choice Perspective on the Economies of Crime. Southern Economic Journal, 61(1), 161-168. doi. 10.2307/1060137
Block, W. (1983). Public Goods and Externalities: The Case of Roads, The Journal of Libertarian Studies: An Interdisciplinary Review, 7(1), 1-34. [Retrieved from].
Block, W. (1988). Comment on Leland Yeager on Subjectivism, Review of Austrian Economics, 2, 199-208. [Retrieved from].
Block, W. (1993). Drug Prohibition: A Legal and Economic Analysis, Journal of Business Ethics, 12(9), 689-700. doi. 10.1007/BF00881383
Block, W. (1996). Drug Prohibition, Individual Virtue and Positive Economics, Review of Political Economy, 8(4), 433-436. doi. 10.1080/09538259600000077
Block, W.E. (2000). Watch Your Language, February 21. [Retrieved from].
Block, W. (2000). Word Watch, April 20. [Retrieved from].
Block, W.E. (2002). All Government is Excessive: A Rejoinder to ‘In Defense of Excessive Government’ by Dwight Lee, Journal of Libertarian Studies, 16(3), 35-82. [Retrieved from].
Block, W. (2003). National Defense and the Theory of Externalities, Public Goods and Clubs.” The Myth of National Defense: Essays on the Theory and History of Security Production, Hoppe, Hans-Hermann, ed., Auburn: Mises Institute, pp. 301-334; [Retrieved from].
Block W.E. (2014). Book review essay of Steven Pinker’s: The better angels of our nature: Why violence has declined. New York, N.Y. Penguin; Part II.” [Retrieved from]. Management Education Science Technology Journal MEST, 2(1), 141-160. doi. 10.12709/mest.02.02.01.15
Block, W.E., Wingfield, K., & Whitehead, R. (2003). Re-Evaluating America’s Failing Drug Control Laws: A Legal, Philosophical, and Economic Proposal, Oklahoma City Law Review, 28(1), 119-159.
Block, W. (2009a). Toward a Libertarian Theory of Guilt and Punishment for the Crime of Statism. in Hulsmann, Jorg Guido & Stephan Kinsella, (eds)., Property, Freedom and Society: Essays in Honor of Hans-Hermann Hoppe, Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute, pp. 137-148; [Retrieved from]. or [Retrieved from].
Block, W. (2009b). Libertarian punishment theory: working for, and donating to, the state. Libertarian Papers, [Retrieved from].
Blumenson, E., & Nilsen, E. (1998). Policing for Profit: The Drug War’s Hidden Economic Agenda.” The University of Chicago Law Review, 65(1), 1-81. [Retrieved from].
Buchanan, J.M., & Thirlby, G.F. (1981). L.S.E. Essays on Cost, New York: New York University Press.
Buchanan, J.M. (1969). Cost and Choice: An Inquiry into Economic Theory, Chicago: Markham.
Buchanan, J.M. (1979). "The General Implications of Subjectivism in Economics," in What Should Economists Do?, Indianapolis: Liberty Press.
Butos, W., & Koppl, R. (1997). The varieties of subjectivism: Keynes, Hayek on expectations. History of Political Economy, 29(2), 327-359. doi. 10.1215/00182702-29-2-327
Chi, K.A.Y. (2002). Follow the Money: Getting to the Root of the Problem with Civil Asset Forfeiture in California. California Law Review, 90(5), 1635-1673. doi. 10.15779/Z38KH8W
Cordato, R.E. (1989). Subjective Value, Time Passage, and the Economics of Harmful Effects, Hamline Law Review, 12(2), 229-244.
Cowen, T. (1988). The Theory of Market Failure: A Critical Examination, Fairfax, VA: George Mason University Press.
Cussen, M., & Block, W.E. (2000). Legalize Drugs Now! An Analysis of the Benefits of Legalized Drugs, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 59(3), 525-536. doi. 10.1111/1536-7150.00041
De Jasay, A. (1989). Social Contract, Free Ride: A Study of the Public Goods Problem. Oxford, England: Oxford University Press;
DiLorenzo, T.J. (1990). The Subjectivist Roots of James Buchanan's Economics, The Review of Austrian Economics, 4, 180-195. doi. 10.1007/978-94-017-3454-7_6
Doyle, C. (2008). Crime and Forfeiture. Nova Science Publishers, pp. 1-89. [Retrieved from].
Ehrlich, I. (1972). The Deterrent Effect of Criminal Law Enforcement, Journal of Legal Studies, 1(2), 259-276.
Ehrlich, I. (1973). Participation in Illegitimate Activities - A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation, Journal of Political Economy, 81(3), 521-565. doi. 10.1086/260058
Ehrlich, I. (1974). Participation in Illegitimate Activities - An Economic Analysis, in The Economics of Crime and Punishment, Becker & Landes, eds., Columbia University Press, New York, pp. 68-134.
FBI Crime Statistics, 2012. [Retrieved from].
Friedman, M. (1992). The Drug War as a Socialist Enterprise. Friedman & Szasz on Liberty and Drugs, edited and with a Preface by Arnold S. Trebach and Kevin B. Zeese. Washington, D.C.: The Drug Policy Foundation; [Retrieved from].
Friedman, M., & Szasz, T.S. (1992). Friedman & Szasz On Liberty and Drugs: Essays on the Free Market and Prohibition. Eds. Arnold S. Trebach, & Kevin B. Zeese. Drug Policy Foundation Press
Garrison, R. (1985). A Subjectivist Theory of a Capital Using Economy, in O'Driscoll, Gerald P. & Rizzo, Mario, The Economics of Time and Ignorance, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Guide to Equitable Sharing for State and Local Law Enforcement Agencies. 2009. U.S. Department of Justice, pp. 1-47; [Retrieved from].
Gunning, J.P. (1990). The New Subjectivist Revolution: An Elucidation and Extension of Ludwig von Mises's Contribution to Economic Theory, Savage, MD: Rowan and Littlefield.
Hayek, F.A. (1979). The Counter-Revolution of Science, 2nd ed. Indianapolis, IN: LibertyPress.
Holcombe, R. (1997). A Theory of the Theory of Public Goods, Review of Austrian Economics, 10(1), 1-10. [Retrieved from].
Hoppe, H.H. (1989). Fallacies of the Public Goods Theory and the Production of Security, The Journal of Libertarian Studies, 9(1), 27-46. [Retrieved from].
Hummel, J. (1990). National Goods vs. Public Goods: Defense, Disarmament and Free Riders, The Review of Austrian Economics, 4, 88-122. [Retrieved from].
Kelly, B.D., & Kole, M.A. (2013). The Effects of Asset Forfeiture on Policing: A Panel Approach. Economic Inquiry, 54(1), 558-575. doi. 10.1111/ecin.12232
Kinsella, S. (1996). Punishment and Proportionality: the Estoppel Approach, The Journal of Libertarian Studies, 12(1), 51-74; [Retrieved from].
Kinsella, S. (1997). A Libertarian Theory of Punishment and Rights, Loyola of Los Angels Law Review, 607-45. [Retrieved from]
Kirzner, I. (1986). Subjectivism, Intelligibility and Economic Understanding, New York: New York University Press.
Levesque, J. (2014). Property Rights-When Reform Is Not Enough: A Look inside the Problems Created by the Civil Asset Forfeiture Reform Act of 2000. Western New England Law Review, 37, 59-89. [Retrieved from].
Mast, B.D., Benson, B.L., & Rasmussen, D.W. (2000). Entrepreneurial Police and Drug Enforcement Policy. Public Choice, 104(3), 285-308. doi. 10.1023/A:1005183918319
Miller, J.M., & Selva, L.H. (1994). Drug Enforcement’s Double-Edged Sword: An Assessment of Asset Forfeiture Programs. Justice Quarterly, 11(2), 245-267. doi. 10.1080/07418829400092271
Mises, L. ([1922] 1981). Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis. Translated by J. Kahane. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.
Mises, L. (1944). Bureaucracy. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Mises, L. ([1949] 1998). Human Action, Scholars’ Edition. Auburn: Mises Institute. [Retrieved from].
Rizzo, M.J. (1979). Uncertainty, Subjectivity, and the Economic Analysis of Law, in Mario J. Rizzo (ed.), Time, Uncertainty, and Disequilibrium, Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, pp. 71-90
Moores, E. (2009). Reforming the Civil Asset Forfeiture Reform Act. Arizona Law Review, 51, 777-803. [Retrieved from].
Naylor, R.T. (2000). Wash-out: A Critique of Follow-The-Money Methods in Crime Control Policy. Crime, Law & Social Change, 32(1), 1-58. doi. 10.1023/A:1008386203362
Olson, C.B. (1979). Law in Anarchy. Libertarian Forum. 12(6), [Retrieved from].
Osterfeld, D. (1989). Anarchism and the Public Goods Issue: Law, Courts and the Police, The Journal of Libertarian Studies, 9(1), 47-68. [Retrieved from].
Pasour, Jr., E.C. (1981). The Free Rider as a Basis for Government Intervention, The Journal of Libertarian Studies, 5(4), 453-464; [Retrieved from].
Pimentel, D. (2012). Forfeitures Revisited: Bringing Principle to Practice in Federal Court. Nevada Law Journal, 13, 3-59. [Retrieved from].
Rizzo, M.J. (1980). The Mirage of Efficiency, Hofstra Law Review, 8(3), 641-658. [Retrieved from].
Rothbard, M.N. (1977). Punishment and Proportionality. R.E. Barnett & J. Hagel, III (eds.), Assessing the Criminal: Restitution, Retribution, and the Legal Process. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Co., pp. 259 270.
Rothbard, M.N. (1979). Comment: The Myth of Efficiency, in Mario J. Rizzo (ed.), Time, Uncertainty, and Disequilibrium, Lexington, MA: Lexington Books: pp. 91-96.
Rothbard, M.N. (1997a). The Logic of Action: Applications and Criticism from the Austrian School, Vol. II, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
Rothbard, M.N. (1997b). Toward a Reconstruction of Utility and Welfare Economics, in The Logic of Action: Method, Money and the Austrian School, Vol. I, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, pp. 211-254.
Rothbard M. (1998). The Ethics of Liberty. New York: New York University Press. [Retrieved from].
Rothschild, D.Y. & Block, W.E. (2016). Don't steal, the government hates competition: The problem with civil asset forfeiture. The Journal of Private Enterprise, 31(1), 45-56.
Rulli, L.S. (2001). The Long Term Impact of CAFRA: Expanding Access to Counsel and Encouraging Greater Use of Criminal Forfeiture. Federal Sentencing Reporter, 14(2), Forfeiture: Recent Reform and Future Outlook, University of California Press: Vera Institute of Justice, pp. 87-97.
Salerno, J.T. (2015). The War on Cash Destroys a Small Entrepreneur. May 13. [Retrieved from]. or [Retrieved from].
Schmidtz, D. (1991). The Limits of Government: An Essay on the Public Goods Argument, Boulder Co: Westview Press.
Sechrest, L. (2003). Privateering and National Defense: Naval Warfare for Private Profit. pp. 239-74, The Myth of National Defense: Essays on the Theory and History of Security Production, edited by Hans-Hermann Hoppe, published by the Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, Alabama, 2003.
Sechrest, L. (2004a). “Public Goods and Private Solutions in Maritime History. The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics. 7(2), 3-27. [Retrieved from]. Or [Retrieved from].
Sechrest, L. (2004). Private Provision of Public Goods: Theoretical Issues and Some Examples from Maritime History, ICFAI Journal of Public Finance, August, 2(3), 45- 73. [Retrieved from].
Sechrest, L. (2007). Privately Funded and Built U.S. Warships in the Quasi-War of 1797-1801, The Independent Review, 12(1), 101-113.
Sherman, L.W. (1983). Patrol Strategies for Police, in Crime and Public Policy, edited by James Q. Wilson. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies Press, pp.145-163.
Spooner, L. (2009). Vices are Not Crimes: A Vindication of Moral Liberty. Mises Daily Articles, 1-15. [Retrieved from].
Stringham, E. (2008). Economic Value and Cost Are Subjective. in The Handbook of Austrian Economics, Peter Boettke (editor), Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing; [Retrieved from].
Szasz, T.S. (1985). Ceremonial Chemistry: The Ritual Persecution of Drugs, Addicts, and Pushers. Holmes Beach, Fla. : Learning Publications.
Szasz, T.S. (1992). Our Right to Drugs: The Case For a Free Market, New York: Praeger.
Thornton, M. (1991). The Economics of Prohibition, Salt Lake City: University of Utah Press.
Tinsley, P. (1998-1999). With Liberty and Justice for All: A Case for Private Police, Journal of Libertarian Studies, 14(1), 95-100; [Retrieved from].
Warchol, G.L., & Johnson, B.R. (1996). Guilty Property: A Quantitative Analysis of Civil Asset Forfeiture. American Journal of Criminal Justice, 21(1), 61-81. doi. 10.1007/BF02887430
Whitehead, R., & Block, W.E. (2003). Taking the assets of the criminal to compensate victims of violence: a legal and philosophical approach, Wayne State University Law School Journal of Law in Society, 5(1), 229-254.
Williams, M.R., Holcomb, J.E., & Kovandzic, T.V..(2011). Civil Asset Forfeiture, Equitable Sharing, and Policing for Profit in the United States. Journal of Criminal Justice, 39, 273-285. doi. 10.1016/j.jcrimjus.2011.02.010
Williams, M.R., Holcomb, J.E., & Kovandzic, T.V. (2010). Policing for Profit: The Abuse of Civil Asset Forfeiture. Institute for Justice. [Retrieved from].
Worrall, J.L. (2004). The Civil Asset Forfeiture Reform Act of 2000: A Sheep in Wolf’s Clothing?, Policing: An International Journal of Police Strategies & Management, 27(2), 220-240. doi. 10.1108/13639510410536832
Worrall, J.L. (2008). Problem-Oriented Guides for Police Response Guides Series Guide No. 7: Asset Forfeiture. Center for Problem-Oriented Policing, The U.S. Department of Justice. [Retrieved from].
DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1453/jsas.v3i3.912
Refbacks
- There are currently no refbacks.
....................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................... Journal of Social and Administrative Sciences - J. Adm. Soc. Sci. - JSAS - www.kspjournals.org
ISSN: 2149-0406
Editor: editor-jsas@kspjournals.org Secretarial: secretarial@kspjournals.org Istanbul - Turkey.
Copyright © KSP Library